Stay up to date with notifications from The Independent

Notifications can be managed in browser preferences.

Stephen Pollard: This is the worst way to protect the Third World

If it were not for copyright protection, India's innovative software industry would not even exist

Tuesday 17 September 2002 00:00 BST
Comments

Clare Short took a major risk yesterday. She exposed us all to a mass outbreak of narcolepsy when she used two words that have long had the power to cure insomnia: intellectual property. Allow me to explain why she took that risk and why, far from sending people to sleep, intellectual property is causing some of the most fevered debates on the planet.

Today in Geneva, the World Trade Organisation's "Trips Council" is meeting to discuss how developing countries can gain access to affordable medicines. Trips – the Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights Agreement – is the WTO's attempt to draw up an international agreement on intellectual property.

As part of that process, Ms Short was in Geneva yesterday to launch the report of the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights (CIPR), a de facto Royal Commission (with members from the UK, US, Argentina and India) set up by Ms Short to look at the impact of intellectual property on the developing world. Far from being a dry subject, intellectual property (IP) is the single most important factor in accelerating or blocking – depending on how you look at it – economic growth in developing countries.

The CIPR report argues that, while patents are indeed critical in providing an incentive for the private sector to develop medicines that benefit rich and poor alike, the IP system "hardly plays any role in stimulating research on diseases particularly prevalent in developing countries". Worse, it worries that patent protection can stall economic growth in poor countries because it's an inappropriate mechanism for economies that are very different to the developed world's. As the CIPR puts it: "Developed countries often proceed on the assumption that what is good for them is likely to be good for developing countries. But, in the case of developing countries, more and stronger protection is not necessarily better".

It sounds sensible. A Bangladeshi peasant farmer, after all, not only has a very different job to a German software programmer, he also operates in a very different economic and legal environment. Thus the report argues that intellectual property rights should be looser in the developing world.

But its analysis is completely wrong. It is those poorer countries that most need the protection of IP rights. In countries such as India, Brazil and South Africa, all of which have burgeoning knowledge-based industries, investment and growth have been driven at astonishing speed precisely because of the patents and copyright that underpin innovation and creativity. Patents and copyright are part of the solution to poverty, not its cause. The very worst thing that could happen would be for IP rights to be diminished.

Take the relative strengths of India's software and pharmaceutical industries. Its innovative software industry has grown from nothing to a multibillion dollar enterprise in 10 years. But the industry would not even exist were it not for the country's strong copyright protection, which allows innovators to profit from their work. India's pharmaceutical industry, on the other hand, is almost entirely concentrated on manufacturing generic drugs, simply copying existing pharmaceuticals. It carries out virtually no research and development. Why? Because the absence of patent protection means that there is no incentive to innovate, since anyone can copy and manufacture any new drug.

Intellectual property is a fundamental part of that process and has underpinned much of the world's economic development in the past century and a half. Patents provide incentives for entrepreneurs to invent new technologies; copyright provides incentives for cultural achievements, from works of art to great literature.

Just as property rights in land create incentives to improve that land, so property rights in the products of the intellect provide incentives to develop better products. Incentives are created for the initial invention as well as the further development and improvement of that invention.

Countries that still have weak IP protection should thus be strengthening it, not weakening it as the CIPR report advocates. Strengthening IP protection would stimulate local invention and encourage overseas IP-holders to engage in joint projects and investments. Talented and knowledgeable people would therefore be less likely to go overseas in order to use their skills.

Trade liberalisation, which has been a fundamental driver of economic development, enabling consumers and producers to benefit from trade with one another across borders, needs also to be accompanied by agreements on international IP protection. Without such developments, the opening up of borders simply makes it easier to import copies of protected goods, so undermining local producers and innovators.

It's easy to assume that IP protection is just an excuse for big business and the developed world to keep the developing world down. The truth, as ever, is more complicated. Intellectual property is not some abstruse, esoteric aspect of law; it's about the very fundamentals of prosperity.

stephenipollard@hotmail.com

The writer is a senior fellow at the Centre for the New Europe

Join our commenting forum

Join thought-provoking conversations, follow other Independent readers and see their replies

Comments

Thank you for registering

Please refresh the page or navigate to another page on the site to be automatically logged inPlease refresh your browser to be logged in